ECB, Euro, USD, Interest Rates

ECB, Euro, USD, Interest Rates
David R. Kotok
Cumberland, January 24, 2015

 

 

After a two-and-a-half-year wait for “whatever it takes,” the quantitative easing (QE) announced this week by the European Central Bank (ECB) is different from the QE undertaken by the Federal Reserve (Fed) during and after the financial crisis and now completed. The European action comes in the aftermath of the Fed’s programs and is a European attempt to confront complex economics. 

In the 2008–2014 Fed version, QE injected liquidity into markets that were frozen. More QE was then piled on as the Fed expanded its holdings of federally backed securities. A single sovereign guaranteed that debt, and that was the United States government.

The QE process quickly drove the short-term interest rate to zero but not below zero. Over time the longer-term interest rates followed a similar path to lower and lower levels. The reduction in interest rates translated to reduced mortgage and corporate-financing costs. The process has continued for seven years. A refinancing apparatus could then develop in the US economy as one agent after another took advantage of persistently lower interest rates. Lenders adjusted to the new notion of lower interest rates for longer periods. Investors were hit by financial repression as their savings instruments matured and rolled over into lower interest rates. That process is ongoing in 2015.

In the US, behaviors changed over the course of seven years. Positions that were initially viewed as being temporary started to seem permanent.

Forecasters warned, “The Fed is printing all this money; we’ll have a big inflation; interest rates will skyrocket; and the economy and markets will go in the tank.” The warnings were repeated ad infinitum in the media. They were debated by some.

Cumberland Advisors numbered among the debaters. We argued “no.” We were in the minority. Over and over again we heard predictions of hyperinflation and higher interest rates. We said “no.” We heard all of the outcomes that would be terrible as a result of QE. We said “no.” Seven years on, the debate continues, with the detractors predicting doom. Meanwhile, in the United States, interest rates are very low. There is minimal inflation. The economic recovery is strengthening. The American stock markets reached all-time highs within the last month. 

The detractors are still predicting the end of the world. Someday they may be correct. But not in January, 2015. At Cumberland we still say “no.” Not yet!

Seven years later in the US we can now add a major oil shock to the economic positives. With QE-induced refinancing in place and with growing intensity in our economic recovery, the outlook is simply marvelous. In 2015, our growth will be above 3%, employment will improve, and inflation will remain low. The positive trends continue and are becoming more robust. In addition, we have the world’s strongest major reserve currency, with a long run still ahead of it. And we have a better fiscal balance in the US than most nations enjoy.

In the US, QE was controversial and still is. Meanwhile, look at results. It worked.

Examine the same issues in the Eurozone and the ECB, and we see a different picture than in the US.

The ECB will be acquiring over 1 trillion in sovereign debt. Their allocation method is quite different from the Fed’s. They have to deal with the sovereign debts of different countries that have different levels of creditworthiness, ranging from junk-bond status in Greece to the highest-grade status in Germany and Finland. There is no inflation and no expectation of inflation in the Eurozone. Interest rates for the debt of the very highest-grade sovereigns are already next to zero in the Eurozone. The same is true for nearby sovereigns like Sweden and for Switzerland.

In all of Europe, interest rates on longer-term sovereign debt are remarkably low and mostly lower than in the US. Italy’s 10-year benchmark sovereign debt touched 1.4% on Friday. Spain reached 1.25%. In Germany, the sovereign benchmark for the Eurozone, the 30-year bond yield is 1%, and the 10-year note is 0.2%. All German maturities under 5 years are trading at negative yields.

QE by the ECB will not lower interest rates — they are already at or near zero. In fact, the ECB has announced it will acquire sovereign debt even if the yield is negative. Think about that. The central bank will be creating money in order to pay the various sovereign governments for the privilege of buying their debt. That is how a negative interest rate works.

Meanwhile, the fiscal situation in Europe is still under repair, a process that will take many years. In countries like France, a great portion of the economy, more than half, is driven by the government. Italy is another case study of a huge burden of social promises and a deficient funding mechanism to pay for them. Greece is a mess without easy answers. Others in Europe no longer care whether Greece exits the Eurozone. Many hope that they do, because it is nearly impossible to throw any country out. Grexit (the term for a Greece exit from the Eurozone) would be welcomed by other peripheral countries, although the celebration in those countries would be a quiet one due to the observance of political correctness.

To be blunt, the divisions in Europe cannot be healed by QE. The promises that are expensed as social benefit payments act to reduce productivity and restrain growth. This fiscal reality cannot be cured by QE. In fact, there is no liquidity shortage in Europe for QE to fix. QE is not a reform mechanism for euro-sclerosis. QE cannot cure sick governance. It cannot lower interest rates when they are at zero. It cannot stimulate credit expansion when there is no credit demand. If zero interest rates won’t work, a continuation of zero interest rates also won’t work.

So what does QE do?

In Europe, QE transfers the fiscal failure of the sovereign states involved to the monetary authority, the European Central Bank. The ECB creates money. The money is used to buy the sovereign debt of Eurozone members at an interest rate of zero or near-zero. The sovereign debt the ECB buys is likely to be held for years. It must be viewed as a permanent structure, just as it has become in Japan. The ECB will not be “tapering” in this decade. Maybe it will do so in the next decade. The proceeds of the issuance of sovereign debt will fund the social promises that governments cannot otherwise keep. Contrast that situation with that in the US, where the annualized government deficit is nearly $1 trillion smaller than it was at its worst in 2009.

In Europe, QE is a circular mechanism. It has no multiplier in the credit arena. It inspires no productivity gain from investment by the private sector. It is merely circular.

So, if it is circular, why have QE?

There is one element that works with QE, whether in the US or Europe. We have seen it work in the US, and we will see it work in Europe. QE withdraws duration from the market and transfers it onto the government’s books. The market then seeks to replace the duration in its asset mix. That is why asset prices rise when QE occurs: asset prices rise when duration is in demand, and they fall when duration is in supply. When central banks extract duration from the market, it has to be replaced with something else. Stocks are long-duration assets. Real estate is a long-duration asset. Collectibles and precious metals are long-duration assets. Patents and other forms of intellectual property rights are long-duration assets. Cash is not long-duration. The duration of cash is one day.

In the US, QE has resulted in record stock market prices. They are still rising. QE has resulted in higher real estate prices. They are still rising. QE adds to the upward direction of asset prices and the accumulation of wealth by the wealthy. We see it in the statistics that track wealth and in the statistics that are derived from the income streams owned by the wealthy.

Wealth effects operate with a time lag. There is a slight transfer each year from accumulated wealth into consumption spending and hence into economic growth. It is a small percentage. From a higher and rising stock market, we estimate that transfer to be 1%-2% in any given year. If stock market wealth rises and there is a positive and permanent wealth effect of $100 over the course of the year, an additional $1 to $2 in annual spending transfers slowly to economic growth. We see that at work in the US. We will see it at work in Europe as well.

There is a higher transfer when real estate prices rise and are viewed as permanently heading higher. The financing mechanism for housing has a multiplier that is greater than the financing mechanism applied to financial assets. That makes sense since the credit multiplier for housing is higher than for stocks. For example, stocks can sit in your 401(k) unleveraged, while houses are mortgaged and do not sit in 401(k)s. Therefore the transmission mechanism from higher housing wealth is more robust than the transmission mechanism from higher stock prices. Yale Professor Bob Shiller notes that housing wealth effects can reach 3% to 5% a year. We already see some of those effects in the US, thanks to QE. As housing becomes more robust, we will see more of the positive housing wealth effects in the US. We will see a little of this happening in the Eurozone.

The conclusion is that the extended and predictable period of QE in Europe will give some positive stimulus to economic growth via the wealth-effect transmission method. It will not be a panacea for Europe’s problems. Monetary policy cannot fix fiscal policy errors or the suppression of production by governments, but monetary policy can raise asset prices. In Europe it will do so. In the US it already has done so, and the rise is not over.

At Cumberland Advisors, we remain fully invested in the US stock market in our exchange-traded fund (ETF) strategies. We are focused on domestic businesses. Our largest overweight is the utility sector. It is 95% domestic, so its corporate entities do not have to worry about foreign currency translations impacting their earnings. The sector benefits from a slowly and steadily growing US economy. It pays dividend yields that exceed the riskless interest rate from Treasury notes. It is defensive and less volatile than other sectors in a period when volatility is rising.

Our international ETF strategies have a majority of components that are currency hedged. Our outlook for the dollar is a prolonged period of strengthening. We expect a lot of adjustment vis-à-vis the other currencies that are involved in the present historic restructuring of monetary policy. Those currencies will weaken relative to the dollar. It is conceivable that the yen could reach 135 or 150 to the dollar over a period of several years. It is conceivable that the euro-dollar exchange rate could be 1.00, 0.90, or 0.85 over the next two or three years. The range of possibilities is unknown, and the confidence intervals on such estimates are very wide.

Imagine a world where the US central bank policy rate is 1% and the Eurozone central bank policy rate is minus 0.2%. The math suggests that the dollar would then strengthen by 1.2% a year against the euro. Compare the current 10-year German Bund at 0.2% to the 10-year US note. The difference is 1.7%. That math suggests the dollar will strengthen 17% against the euro over the next 10 years. Please note that this is a very simplified model. The actual way this comparison is done is much more complex, but the concept is the same. Interest-rate differentials explain longer-term movements in currency exchange rates.

We cannot fully estimate what euro-dollar exchange rates will be. The truth is, nobody knows.

We anticipate the volatilities associated with this massive transition in policy to reach new levels. That means lots of activity in managed portfolios and a need for the portfolio manager to be nimble and move quickly when required.

Volatility is bidirectional. It is scary when it causes prices to accelerate if they fall.  It is frightening at inflection points. And it is exhilarating when it enables prices to head upward. Expect all of the above in 2015.

~~~

David R. Kotok, Chairman and Chief Investment Officer, Cumberland

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

What's been said:

Discussions found on the web:
  1. Futuredome commented on Jan 25

    At some point, people will figure out the Fed doesn’t print money. Their power is trying to manipulate the interest rate of money already printed. If I was Janet Yellen, I would make this perfectly clear. It would probably rattle market badly however. Right now, there is a scarcity of dollars and has been since the mid-90’s.

    For example. If Congress/President announced a 10 trillion dollar infrastructure plan……all spent by printing Dollars. That would rattle markets and cause the Fed to react by raising interest rates due to all the excess dollar floating around the country. LBJ did that in the 60’s with guns and butter. He didn’t borrow, but printed a lot of dollars, which eventually caused France to ask for Gold in return, rather than Dollars. That eventually led to the collapse of BW and the Nixon abandonment of gold entirely.

  2. b_thunder commented on Jan 25

    Kotok:
    “So what does QE do?
    In Europe, QE transfers the fiscal failure of the sovereign states involved to the monetary authority, the European Central Bank. The ECB creates money. The money is used to buy the sovereign debt of Eurozone members at an interest rate of zero or near-zero. The sovereign debt the ECB buys is likely to be held for years. It must be viewed as a permanent structure, just as it has become in Japan. The ECB will not be “tapering” in this decade. Maybe it will do so in the next decade. The proceeds of the issuance of sovereign debt will fund the social promises that governments cannot otherwise keep. ”

    Question:
    isn’t monetizing gov’t debt explicitly prohibited by the EMU agreement? Monetizing the gov’t debt for decades on rather than revitalizing economy and taxing new incomes and capital gains – what can go wrong???

    Kotok:
    “Wealth effects operate with a time lag. There is a slight transfer each year from accumulated wealth into consumption spending and hence into economic growth. It is a small percentage. From a higher and rising stock market, we estimate that transfer to be 1%-2% in any given year. If stock market wealth rises and there is a positive and permanent wealth effect of $100 over the course of the year, an additional $1 to $2 in annual spending transfers slowly to economic growth. We see that at work in the US. We will see it at work in Europe as well.”

    Question: so in 2014 the Fed has engineered a total net worth gain of $5-6 trillion, and likely by over 20 trillion since 2010, while the MEDIAN family net worth has DECLINED by 2%: http://www.usatoday.com/story/money/personalfinance/2014/09/18/stock-gains-lift-us-household-wealth-to-a-record/15830331/
    And what is the payoff? Kotok says that the payoff is $1 to $2 in annual spending transfers. So for $5 trillion of net worth gained by the top 10%, the rest will spend an additional $50-100 billion, which is 0.3 to 0.6% of GDP! And this is supposed to be the best way to grow GDP by 0.3%-0.6%, really? REALLY?
    Let’s summarize: the top 10% (and primarily the top 0.01%) gain $5+ trillions/year, while most families’ wealth shrinks, and the payoff is that the aggregate spending grows by 0.3-0.6% of GDP. And that will go on for year if not decades. And, interestingly enough, Kotok doesn’t list any potential side-effects… I guess nothing can go wrong, nothing at all?

    Another Question: is this the best wealth-transfer scheme ever devised or what? It’s absolutely brilliant! As the organic growth (and profits) in the West dwindle, the solution is to create a bubble, crash the market and destroy the wealth of the middle class, and then suck the rest of the remaining wealth over the following decades while claiming to be “fighting deflation.” Those half-literate commies like Chavez could never come up with such a plan! You’ve got to have a PhDs from a leading schools plus Goldman Sachs work experience!

    So, does anyone else think that the actions of the Central Banks have led the West to a point where we’re just one economic “shock” away from the proverbial pitchforks?

    http://www.politico.com/magazine/story/2014/06/the-pitchforks-are-coming-for-us-plutocrats-108014.html

  3. taxman100 commented on Jan 25

    I agree with Cumberland Advisers analysis with one exception. They still see the stagnation as a supply side issue, with competition and cost of labor and social costs as the main problem. My opinion is the private and public sector de-leveraging, and cost cutting is creating the low growth environment. If we can just get our costs low enough then people will start buying again. But that cost cutting is undermining the demand side of the equation. If everyone spends less, incomes are lower, demand is lower, inflation is lower, and interest rate are lower. It is a downward spiral. Give every household 1000 euros and let them either pay off some debt or buy something. Do it with tax cuts or just send them a check and demand will go up a little. Austerity is what you do when the economy is booming to deflate not during a depression.

  4. DeDude commented on Jan 26

    The way QE worked in US was to keep rates on consumer debt (particularly housing) low and thereby stimulate consumer demand. In the government sector effects were minimal although the lower rates held back the austerity fools a little, by keeping the cost of government debt low.

    The rates in most of Europe are exceptionally low and it is hard to imagine a lot of rate reduction on the housing/consumer debt side – except in the south. It may well be that QE is less effective in Europe than it was in US.

    By the way it is nice to see someone like Kotok admitting that the “wealth effect” is a miniscule 1-2%. It is certainly true but also not what his clients like to hear. There is no doubt that QE drive up asset prices but the idea that the wealth effect would be a major transmission line of QE to GDP growth does not hold much water for the short run. The calculation of “b_thunder” show that point very nicely. QE is about demand from consumers in debt. At this time economic growth is all about demand. Actually in a world with fiat money and a stock market, it takes immense incompetence to get to a point where supply is even a small part of growth problems.

Posted Under