Is finance a powerful driver of growth?

Is finance a powerful driver of growth?
Saleem Bahaj, Iren Levina and Jumana Saleheen
Bank of England, 20 JULY 2016

 

 

 

Since the financial crisis the UK has experienced a period of weak productivity growth, weak investment coupled with a decline in credit to non-financial sectors of the economy.  But there is debate about the direction of causality: did low growth and other structural factors mean firms and households wanted to borrow less – as argued by Martin Wolf?  Or did the financial sector offer too few funds to the real economy in the wake of the crisis as banks tried to repair their balance sheets. Alternatively, the financial system may not be functioning properly in general, if much of the financial sector’s activity contributes little to the betterment of lives and efficiency of business – a point made by John Kay.

In this post, we analyse whether there has been enough finance to enable productive investment?  This question was posed to the Bank of England by the Government last year, as part of its ‘productivity plan’.  One concern is: Is the financial sector is holding back UK productivity?  This post summarises our own insights on this topic, partly drawing on the recent Bank Discussion Paper.   Importantly, our interpretation is blurred by the lack of data.  But let’s start with the really interesting things we uncovered.

What we know

To measure the concept of finance for productive investment, we split our thinking into two questions:

(Q1) Are there unexploited productive investment opportunities in the UK?  We found no conclusive evidence of investment deficiency.

We think of investment as productive as long as the expected marginal social return to investment is greater than or equal to the expected marginal social cost of capital.  Simply put, this means what society as a whole gets out of investment is more than what it puts in.  Building a bridge that is heavily used is a productive investment, but a ‘bridge to nowhere’ would be an unproductive investment.

The UK capital stock is low relative to other countries (see Chart 1).  If we went out today and burned down every building, scrapped every bit of machinery and fried every hard drive, the cost of replacing all that stuff (lucky for us) would be cheaper as a share of the economy in the UK than for other developed countries.  A possible reason for this finding is that the financial system is not giving the funds that firms need to buy new equipment.  But there are other alternative explanations as well – the UK has a more flexible labour market which may make it more labour intensive (companies go for workers over machines); and the UK economy is more service oriented,  associated with less on machines and more on intangible capital such as software, data and intellectual property.  It is well known (e.g. see The Conference Board) that official measures of the capital stock are generally less good at measuring intangible capital than they are at measuring tangible capital.

Another way of testing if the UK is investing too little – and leaving productive investment opportunities on the table – is to look at the actual returns on capital.  Typically the more machines a company has, the less return the company gets out of adding a new machine (diminishing marginal returns to scale).   The UK returns to capital paint a more sanguine picture: UK returns to capital at around 12% are bang in line with its peers – Chart 2 – suggesting no obvious underinvestment in the UK.  These data aren’t perfect, however.  The social return to capital has been proxied by the private return, the marginal return by the average return, and the expected return by past actual returns.

Chart 1 Capital-to-output ratios(a)

Chart_1

Sources: Centre for International Data, ONS and Bank of England.
(a)  UK data for 2012-2014 updated using Bank of England estimates (see Oulton and Wallis (2015)). Capital to output ratio is the total economy capital stock (at replacement cost) over GDP.

Chart 2 Net return on capital at replacement cost.

Chart_2

Sources: ONS. Destatis, BEA.  Non-financial corporations’ net operating surplus/net capital stock.

 (Q2) Is there enough finance to ensure productive investment takes place? Yes for the corporate sector as a whole, but not for all firms

The real question of interest here is if investment is low, is the blockage that is stopping investment taking place due to real economy factors – such as globalisation and secular stagnation – or financial factors – such as a lack of access to finance.

The UK non-financial corporate sector as a whole appears to have enough internal funds to cover all their investment.  This can be seen from the green line being above the yellow line in Chart 3.  In fact, the corporate sector has become a net provider of funds to other sectors in recent times – it generates and retains more profit than it invests.  (A point also made in a previous blog – Are firms ever going to empty their war chests?).

What about the funds raised by corporates?  We find that the funds raised vary a lot over time – there are periods of high external finance raised (such as the late 90s), and periods of low finance – but these highs and lows of external finance raised do not generally co-move with the level of investment.  Instead finance raised seems to move together with companies’ financial activities (red and blue lines on Chart 3).  These financial activities include mergers and acquisitions.  But more generally the co-movement of the assets and liabilities side of the corporate balance sheet illustrate the desire of non-financial companies to increasingly behave like financial firms by using the external funds raised to purchase financial assets.

What is true for the sector as a whole is not true for all firms. Large firms, with access to bond and stock markets, don’t appear to have problems financing themselves.  Small firms that do have access to capital markets rely heavily on net equity issuance to finance their business (Chart 4).  But the vast majority of small firms do not have access to market-based finance and are heavily dependent on bank funding or internal funds. Surveys show that small firms’ access to finance remains an issue, but it now affects a smaller proportion of firms than in recent years (Chart 5).

Chart 3 UK PNFCs’ sources and uses of funds

Chart_3
Sources: ONS and Bank calculations. 2015 data are up to Q3.

Chart 4 Net flows of funds and financing surplus as percentage of total assets (listed non-financial SMEs)

Chart_4

Sources: average for listed non-financial SMEs in Thomson Reuters Worldscope/Bank database.

Internal funds are: Cash Flow from Operations (exc. items relating to changes in net working capital). And the financial surplus is that less dividends, less capital expenditure (net of disposal of fixed assets), less acquisitions.

Chart 5 Perceived availability and cost of credit for large and small firms (a)

Chart_5

Sources: Deloitte CFO Survey, FSB Voice of Small Business Index, Bank calculations.

(a)  Net percentage balances for the cost (availability) of credit are calculated as the percentage of respondents reporting that bank credit is ‘cheap’ (available) in the Deloitte CFO Survey for large corporates or is ‘good’ in the Federation of Small Businesses’ (FSB) Voice of Small Business Index for small businesses less the percentage reporting that it is ‘costly’ (‘hard to get’) in the Deloitte CFO Survey for large corporates or ‘poor’ in the FSB Voice of Small Business Index for small businesses.

What we don’t know

One challenge is that the data are not good enough.  The conclusions drawn out above are based on rough proxies that are available in the data.  But there are a number of important questions that remain unanswered.

For example, are firms not investing because their hurdle rates are too high?  Are hurdle rates very “sticky”, taking a long time to adjust to the lower nominal interest environment that we are in today?

We are also interested in finding out whether what is true for the economy as a whole is true for different segments of the economy.  Slicing and dicing the data on returns we find that smaller, younger and cash-poorer firms all had higher rates of return relative to larger, older and cash-rich firms.  But the reasons for this are unclear (Chart 6).  These higher rates of return could reflect the increased riskiness of such firms, requiring them to generate higher returns to compensate for that risk.  Or it could reflect other structural impediments, such as skill shortages or monopoly power.  But we just don’t have enough data to make an assessment. Data on the marginal cost of capital for each of these types of firms would allow us to adjudicate between different hypotheses.

On measuring finance we know how much finance firms actually have (from their balance sheets). What we don’t know is how much they could have raised if they wanted to, and at what price.  What makes things even more complicated is that getting access to external funding – a bank loan, equity or bond issuance – does not necessarily translate into new investment.  In the past firms had raised lots of money, but those funds were used for other activities, such as mergers and acquisitions or stock buybacks (Chart 3). But in other times, such as during the global financial crisis, levels of finance accessible to firms fell sharply, as did investment.The punchline is: money raised by companies is not always a good predictor of investment.What we need is to find out how different types of funds are used and what the funding structure of investment is. For example, what proportion of internal funds is typically used by companies for investment purposes? And does this vary by firm size, age and cash balances?

Chart 6 Rates of return and profit margins across different types of firms

Chart_6

Source:  Bahaj, Foulis and Pinter (2016) using Bureau van Dijk data. Notes: Young is at most 5 years old. Small is less than 50 employees. Cash rich is when cash (as defined on the balance sheet) less overdrafts, divided by turnover is greater than the sample median. The median of the variable is presented over 1996-2012 for each group.

What next?

In an era of big data, we have discovered the presence of big data gaps.  These data gaps may have blurred our bottom line: we have not found any conclusive evidence of investment deficiency in the UK; and the corporate sector as a whole appears to have an adequate supply of finance to fund their desired investment activities.

But our aim is to gain more precision.  We want data that will enable us to build an accurate set of indicators of finance for productive investment.  And we want to be able to measure the supply of finance for productive investment at the disaggregate level as well, as our work has uncovered some notable differences in investment and financing decisions in some sectors of the economy.   Such measures will make it easier to diagnose if weak investment is due to a deficiency of the financial system or due to real economy blockages.  Distinguishing between these is essential to be able to design the most appropriate policy response.

This post is a plea to the economic and data community to help us discover and collect new and better data sources to measure the supply of finance that can be used to exploit productive investment opportunities for different segments of firms.  We also want to encourage frontier research and new methodologies to help better understand the determinants of finance for productive investment.

Saleem Bahaj works in the Bank’s Research Hub, Iren Levina works in the Macro-Financial Risks Division and Jumana Saleheen is Technical Head of Division in the Bank’s Financial Stability Directorate.

If you want to get in touch, please email us at bankunderground@bankofengland.co.uk. You are also welcome to leave a comment below. Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been approved.

Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

Posted Under